Debate continues in the United States, Europe, and throughout the
world about whether the forces of the marketplace can be harnessed in
the interest of environmental protection, in particular, to address the
threat of global climate change. In an essay that appears in the Spring
2012 issue of Daedalus, the journal of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, my colleague, Joseph Aldy, and I take on this question. In the article – “Using the Market to Address Climate Change: Insights from Theory & Experience”
– we investigate the technical, economic, and political feasibility of
market-based climate policies, and examine alternative designs of carbon
taxes, cap-and-trade, and clean energy standards.
The Premise
Virtually
all aspects of economic activity – individual consumption, business
investment, and government spending – affect greenhouse gas emissions
and, therefore, the global climate. In essence, an effective climate
change policy must change the nature of decisions regarding these
activities in order to promote more efficient generation and use of
energy, lower carbon-intensity of energy, and a more carbon-lean
economy.
Basically, there are three possible ways to accomplish
this: (1) mandate that businesses and individuals change their behavior;
(2) subsidize business and individual investment; or (3) price the
greenhouse gas externality proportional to the harms that these
emissions cause.
Harnessing Market Forces by Pricing Externalities
The
pricing of externalities can promote cost-effective abatement, deliver
efficient innovation incentives, avoid picking technology winners, and
ameliorate, not exacerbate, government fiscal conditions.
By
pricing carbon emissions (or, equivalently, the carbon content of the
three fossil fuels – coal, petroleum, and natural gas), the government
provides incentives for firms and individuals to identify and exploit
the lowest-cost ways to reduce emissions and to invest in the
development of new technologies, processes, and ideas that can mitigate
future emissions. A fairly wide variety of policy approaches fall within
the concept of externality pricing in the climate-policy context,
including carbon taxes, cap-and-trade, and clean energy standards.
What About Conventional Regulatory Approaches?
In
contrast, conventional approaches to environmental protection typically
employ uniform mandates to protect environmental quality. Although
uniform technology and performance standards have been effective in
achieving some established environmental goals and standards, they tend
to lead to non-cost-effective outcomes in which some firms use unduly
expensive means to control pollution.
In addition, conventional
technology or performance standards do not provide dynamic incentives
for the development, adoption, and diffusion of environmentally and
economically superior control technologies. Once a firm satisfies a
performance standard, it has little incentive to develop or adopt
cleaner technology. Indeed, regulated firms may fear that if they adopt a
superior technology, the government will tighten the standard.
Given
the ubiquitous nature of greenhouse gas emissions from diverse sources,
it is virtually inconceivable that a standards-based approach could
form the centerpiece of a truly meaningful climate policy. The
substantially higher cost of a standards-based policy may undermine
support for such an approach, and securing political support may require
weakening standards and lowering environmental benefits.
How About Technology Subsidies?
Government
support for lower-emitting technologies often takes the form of
investment or performance subsidies. Providing subsidies for targeting
climate-friendly technologies entails revenues raised by taxing other
economic activities. Given the tight fiscal environment throughout the
developed world, it is difficult to justify increasing (or even
continuing) the subsidies that would be necessary to change
significantly the emissions intensity of economic activity.
Furthermore, by
lowering the cost of energy, climate-oriented technology subsidies can
actually lead to excessive levels of energy supply and consumption.
Thus, subsidies can undermine incentives for efficiency and
conservation, and impose higher costs per ton abated than cost-effective
policy alternatives.
In practice, subsidies are typically
designed to be technology specific. By designating technology winners,
such approaches yield special-interest constituencies focused on
maintaining subsidies beyond what would be socially desirable. They also
provide little incentive for the development of novel, game-changing
technologies.
That said, there is still a role for direct technology policies in combination with externality pricing, as I have argued in a previous essay at this blog.
This is because in addition to the environmental market failure
(appropriately addressed by externality pricing) there exists another
market failure in the climate change context, namely, the public-good
nature of information produced by research and development. I addressed
this in my essay, “Both
Are Necessary, But Neither is Sufficient: Carbon-Pricing and Technology
R&D Initiatives in a Meaningful National Climate Policy.”
Back to Markets, and Some Real-World Experience
Empirical
analysis drawing on actual experience has demonstrated the power of
markets to drive profound changes in the investment and use of
emission-intensive technologies.
The
run-up in gasoline prices in 2008 increased consumer demand for more
fuel-efficient new cars and trucks, while also reducing vehicle miles
traveled by the existing fleet. Likewise, electricity generators responded to the dramatic decline in natural gas prices in 2009 and 2010 by dispatching more electricity from gas plants, resulting in lower CO2 emissions.
Longer-term evaluations of the impacts of energy prices on markets have found that higher prices have induced more innovation – measured by frequency and importance of patents – and increased
the commercial availability of more energy-efficient products,
especially among energy-intensive goods such as air conditioners and
water heaters.
Experience with Externality Pricing
Real-world experience with policies that price externalities has illustrated the effectiveness of market-based instruments. Congestion charges in London, Singapore, and Stockholm
have reduced traffic congestion in busy urban centers, lowered air
pollution, and delivered net social benefits. Likewise, the British Columbia carbon tax has reduced carbon dioxide emissions since 2008.
More prominently, the U.S. sulfur dioxide (SO2) cap-and-trade program has cut SO2 emissions from U.S. power plants by more than 50 percent since 1990, resulting in compliance costs one-half of what they would have been under conventional regulatory mandates.
The success of the SO2 allowance trading program motivated the design and implementation of the European Union’s Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), the world’s largest cap-and-trade program, focused on cutting CO2 emissions from power plants and large manufacturing facilities throughout Europe.
And the 1980s phasedown of lead in gasoline, which reduced the lead content per gallon of fuel, served as an early, effective example of a tradable performance standard.
These
positive experiences have provided ample reason to consider
market-based instruments – carbon taxes, cap-and-trade, and clean energy
standards – as potential approaches to mitigating greenhouse gas
emissions.
The Rubber Hits the Road
The
U.S. political response to possible market-based approaches to climate
policy has been and will continue to be largely a function of issues and structural factors that transcend the scope of environmental and climate policy.
Because a truly meaningful climate policy – whether market-based or
conventional in design – will have significant impacts on economic
activity in a wide variety of sectors and in every region of the
country, it is not surprising that proposals for such policies bring
forth significant opposition, particularly during difficult economic
times.
In addition, U.S. political polarization
– which began some four decades ago and accelerated during the economic
downturn – has decimated what had long been the key political
constituency in Congress for environmental (and energy) action: namely,
the middle, including both moderate Republicans and moderate Democrats.
Whereas congressional debates about environmental and energy policy have
long featured regional politics, they are now largely partisan. In this
political maelstrom, the failure of cap-and-trade climate policy in the
Senate in 2010 was collateral damage in a much larger political war.
Better
economic times may reduce the pace – if not the direction – of
political polarization. And the ongoing challenge of large federal
budgetary deficits may at some point increase the political feasibility
of new sources of revenue. When and if this happens, consumption taxes –
as opposed to traditional taxes on income and investment – could
receive heightened attention; primary among these might be energy taxes,
which, depending on their design, can function as significant climate
policy instruments.
Many environmental advocates would respond
that a mobilizing event will surely precipitate U.S. climate policy
action. But the nature of the climate change problem itself helps
explain much of the relative apathy among the U.S. public and suggests
that any such mobilizing events may come “too late.”
Nearly all
our major environmental laws have been passed in the wake of highly
publicized environmental events or “disasters,” including the
spontaneous combustion of the Cuyahoga River in Cleveland, Ohio, in 1969, and the discovery of toxic substances at Love Canal in Niagara Falls, New York, in the mid-1970s. But note that the day after the Cuyahoga River caught on fire, no article in The Cleveland Plain Dealer
commented that the cause was uncertain, that rivers periodically catch
on fire from natural causes. On the contrary, it was immediately
apparent that the cause was waste dumped into the river by adjacent
industries. A direct consequence of the observed “disaster” was, of
course, the Clean Water Act of 1972.
But
climate change is distinctly different. Unlike the environmental
threats addressed successfully in past U.S. legislation, climate change
is essentially unobservable to the general population. We observe the
weather, not the climate. Until there is an obvious and sudden event –
such as a loss of part of the Antarctic ice sheet leading to a dramatic
sea-level rise – it is unlikely that public opinion in the United States
will provide the bottom-up demand for action that inspired previous
congressional action on the environment over the past forty years.
A Half-Full Glass of Water?
Despite
this rather bleak assessment of the politics of climate change policy
in the United States, it is really much too soon to speculate on what
the future will hold for the use of market-based policy instruments,
whether for climate change or other environmental problems.
On the
one hand, it is conceivable that two decades (1988–2008) of high
receptivity in U.S. politics to cap-and-trade and offset mechanisms will
turn out to be no more than a relatively brief departure from a
long-term trend of reliance on conventional means of regulation.
On
the other hand, it is also possible that the recent tarnishing of
cap-and-trade in national political dialogue will itself turn out to be a
temporary departure from a long-term trend of increasing reliance on
market-based environmental policy instruments. Perhaps the ongoing
interest in these policy mechanisms in California (Assembly Bill 32),
the Northeast (Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative), Europe, and other
countries will eventually provide a bridge to a changed political
climate in Washington.
By Professor
No comments:
Post a Comment